Sevi's Page; Bio, CV & Research

José V. Rodríguez Mora

Mini Bio

Research Papers

Para todos los públicos.

Artículos de divulgación y opinión

Sobre todo en castellano

To top

Mini Bio

Sevi a few years ago

My name is José Vicente Rodríguez Mora (the first two words are my given name, the third and forth are the surname), but most people call me either Sevi (my friends) or by any random combination of the four aforementioned words (almost everybody outside Spain). This randomness in my name is carried to the professional world where I may appear cited in the most imaginative manners... If you are interested in surnames, see below.

Anyway, I was born in Barcelona in 1965. I grew up, and eventually I ended up with a BA in Economics from the Universidad Autónoma de Barcelona. Then I somehow got a Ph.D. from MIT in 1995. Currently I am a Professor of Economics at CUNEF, in Madrid, and at the University of Edinburgh. I have worked in Universitat Pompeu Fabra and the University of Southampton. I visited the IIES (Stockholm University) in 1998-99 and 2000-01, the University of Minnesota and the Minneapolis Fed in 2013-14 and the EIEF in Rome during in 2020-21.

Currently I am trying to think productively on the following issues:

  • Using bank transaction data to understand relevant aspects of the economy.
  • Understanding the relationship between Intergenerational Mobility and Structural Change.
  • Understanding gender wage discrimination.
  • Measuring lifetime inequality and understanding the drivers of inequality.
Sevi in a place that he loves with his most precious things

I have published papers in journals like the American Economic Review, the Review of Economic Studies, the International Economic Review and the European Economic Review. I have also published in specialized journals like the Journal of Public Economics, the Journal of International Economics, the Journal of Economic Growth or Experimental Economics... Perhaps too many specialized journals in too many fields.

Outside the profession, I like to read and write on Nation, State, and its relationship. I actually have tried to do things on these respects, and I have a certain political activism. Not that it matters, and not that I do much, but it makes me feel better with myself, as I observe my society becoming blind and obsessed with an overdose of nationalism and "patriotism".

I also enjoy writing packages for LaTeX, and to read tons of (1) serious history and (2) pop-biology. I read a lot, but I seldom read fiction; except some of the history books and the economics papers, of course.

I have two children. I know I am biased, but I think they are the best shark hunters in the world. When I have the time, I used to relax by being 35 meters under sea level, but now I do it mostly while being 2500 meters above it.

Research Papers

To top

National Accounts in a World of Naturally Occurring Data: A Proof of Concept for Consumption

Joint with Gergely Buda, Vasco M. Carvalho, Stephen Hansen, Álvaro Ortiz and Tomasa Rodrigo

This paper provides a first proof of concept that naturally occurring transaction data, arising from the decentralized activity of millions of economic agents, can be harnessed to produce both traditional national accounts-like objects and novel representative economic statistics. We deploy comprehensive transaction-level data and its associated metadata arising from the universe of Spanish retail accounts of Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria (BBVA). We first organize the resulting 3 billion individual transactions by 1.8 million bank customers in a large and highly detailed representative consumption panel. Based on this, we then show that the aggregation of such data, once organized according to national accounting principles, can reproduce current official statistics on aggregate consumption in the national accounts with a high degree of precision. As a result of the richness of the transaction data, we additionally show that such data can produce novel, highly detailed distributional accounts for consumption which show larger consumption inequality than surveys suggest, particularly in the right tail. Finally, we use the panel nature of the data to offer a non-parametric analysis of individual consumption dynamics which feature a significant degree of mean reversion. Moreover, the distribution of consumption growth has thick tails.

Get the paper

Get the presentation slides

To top

Short and Variable Lags

Joint with Gergely Buda, Vasco M. Carvalho, Giancarlo Corsetti, João B. Duarte, Stephen Hansen, Afonso S. Moura, Álvaro Ortiz, Tomasa Rodrigo and Guilherme Alves da Silva

We study the transmission of monetary policy shocks using daily consumption, corporate sales and employment series. We find that the economy responds at both short and long lags that are variable in economically significant ways. Consumption reacts in one week, reaches a local trough in one quarter, recovers, and declines again after three quarters. Sales follow a similar pattern, but the initial drop, while delayed (one month), is deeper. In contrast, employment falls monotonically for five quarters albeit with a smaller impact reaction. We show that these short lags are masked by time aggregation at lower —quarterly— frequencies.

Get the paper

To top

The Dynamics of the "Great Gatsby Curve", and a look at the curve during the Great Gatsby Era

Joint with Diego Battiston, Stephan Maurer, and Andrei Potlogea

We use linked historical censuses for the US to revisit the relationship between inequality and socioeconomic mobility - the so-called "Great Gatsby Curve". We make three key contributions. First, we confirm the presence of a positive relationship between inequality and intergenerational persistence (in terms of both income and education) across US counties in a novel historical context, namely the period 1900-1940 (at the time of the Great Gatsby). Second, we exploit the availability of a long panel of measures of both mobility and inequality to introduce and study a "dynamic" version of the Great Gatsby Curve, that relates changes in inequality to changes in socioeconomic mobility. Surprisingly, we find that the relationship between income mobility and inequality is unstable over horizons of two decades, with a slightly negative correlation between changes in inequality and changes in intergenerational income persistence across US counties over the period 1920 to 1940. By contrast, for education, changes in inequality do correlate positively, as expected, with changes in intergenerational persistemce. Finally, we propose novel measures of intergenerational mobility and inequality and use them to analyze the long-run dynamics of the relationship between inequality and socioeconomic mobility. We relate secular changes in income persistence and in inequality over the period 1920 to 2000 and recover the familiar upward sloping Great Gatsby Curve over this long time period.

Get the paper

To top

The Role of Geography in Determining the Inequality between Italians

Joint with Juraj Briskar, Edoardo Di Porto and Cristina Tealdi

The relatively late unification of Italy and the complex history of the peninsula have created a well-known narrative about the prosperous North and the poor South. We show that, despite very large differences in average income levels across provinces, province of birth can only explain 3.4% of lifetime income inequality among Italians, and just 1.8% for males. The figure for females is as high as 10.2%, reflecting regional differences in participation. Differences between rich and poor within provinces are orders of magnitude larger than average differences across them. While tackling regional disparities may have beneficial effects, it will not significantly reduce the level of inequality between Italians.

Get the paper

To top

The Role of Industries in Rising Inequality

Joint with Juraj Briskar, Edoardo Di Porto and Cristina Tealdi

We find that majority of the rise in earnings and wage inequality in Italy between 1985 and 2018 took place between firms and that this was mainly driven by the divergence of pay between firms in different industries. The growth in inequality was extremely concentrated with just 5\% of industries accounting for all of the increase in between-industry variance. The rise in inequality was predominantly driven by rising employment in low-paying industries and to a lesser extent by increasing earnings of high-paying industries. The patterns of rising inequality in Italy are remarkably similar to the ones identified for the USA which suggests a common explanation centred around industry-level labour demand shifts.

Get the paper

To top

Tracking the COVID-19 crisis with high-resolution transaction data

Joint with Vasco M. Carvalho, Juan R. Garcia, Stephen Hansen, Álvaro Ortiz, Tomasa Rodrigo, and Pep Ruiz

RSOS

DOI

Payments systems generate vast amounts of naturally occurring transaction data rarely used for constructing official statistics. We consider billions of transactions from card data from a large bank, Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria, as an alternative source of information for measuring consumption. We show, via validation against official consumption measures, that transaction data complements national accounts and consumption surveys. We then analyse the impact of COVID-19 in Spain, and document: (i) strong consumption responses to business closures, but smaller effects for capacity restrictions; (ii) a steeper decline in spending in rich neighbourhoods; (iii) higher mobility for residents of lower-income neighbourhoods, correlating with increased disease incidence.

Get the paper
To top

The Rise of Meritocracy and the Inheritance of Advantage

Joint with David Comerford (Strathclyde) and Michael J Watts (Edinburgh)

Journal of Economic Growth

DOI

We present a model where more accurate information on the background of individuals facilitates statistical discrimination, increasing inequality and intergenerational persistence in income. Surprisingly, more accurate information on the actual capabilities of workers leads to the same result – firms give increased weight to the more accurate information, increasing inequality, which itself fosters discrimination. The rich take advantage of this through educational investments in their children, and mobility decreases as a consequence of an increase in the ability to reward talent. Using our model to interpret the data suggests that a country like the US might indeed be a land of opportunity for the sufficiently able, as conditional on ability background may have relatively little effect. Nevertheless the US has a relatively low degree of intergenerational mobility precisely because meritocracy facilitates a high correlation of ability with background

Get the paper

To top

The Gains from Economic Integration

Joint with David Comerford (University of Strathclyde)

Economic Policy

DOI

This paper measures the effect of political integration, such as sharing a national state or economic union, on the degree of trade integration. Consistently with previous work, we find large border effects. However, such estimates may be biased and overestimate the effects of borders because of endogeneity: selection into sharing a political space is correlated with affinities for trade. We propose a method to address this and we produce estimates which are closer to the causal effect. We then conduct speculative exercises showing the costs and benefits of the changing levels of integration associated with: the independence of Scotland, Catalonia and the Basque Country from the United Kingdom and Spain [but remaining within the European Union (EU)]; the United Kingdom’s exit from the EU; the break-up of the EU itself and closer integration within the EU so that its internal borders appear similar to the internal borders of individual countries (as opposed to its current state of being simply a closely integrated group of countries). We find that the border effect between countries is an order of magnitude larger than the border effect associated with the EU.

Thus, the costs associated to Scottish Independence appear to be very large, while the costs associated to Brexit are relatively modest. Moreover, Brexit increases the expected costs of Scottish independence, as it places the remaining of the UK even "further" away from an Independent Scotland.

To top

Distortions, Misallocation and the Endogenous Determination of the Size of the Financial Sector

Joint with Christian Bauer

The Economic Journal

DOI

We present a model of heterogeneous firms and misallocation in which financial frictions are partially overcome if more human resources are devoted to intermediation, at the cost of having fewer resources employed in directly productive activities. Not only does an inefficient financial sector result in an inefficient final good sector; an inefficient final good sector results in an inefficient financial sector. Exogenous inefficiencies in the productive sector generate decreased demand for financial services, which translates into a smaller and less efficient financial sector, worsening the resource allocation in the productive sector. This direction of causality seems in line with cross-country evidence.

To top

New Directions in Measuring Intergenerational Mobility

Joint with Maia Guell and Gary Solon

DOI

The Economic Journal

paper we overview some recent literatu re that exemplify several of the cutting edges in research on intergenerational transmission of socioeconomic status and highlight some cross- cutting themes. We also offer a few suggestions for future research

To top

Correlating Social Mobility and Economic Outcomes

Joint with Maia Güell (University of Edinburgh), Michele Pellizzari (University of Geneve) and Giovanni Pica (Universita di Salerno)

The Economic Journal

DOI

We construct comparable measures of intergenerational mobility (IM) for 103 Italian provinces using the methodology of Güell et al. (2007, 2015a) and explore their correlation with a variety of social and economic outcomes. We find that higher IM is positively associated with economic activity, education and social capital and negatively correlated with inequality. Moreover, there is no clear pattern of correlation with other socio-political variables. These results are qualitatively similar to Chetty et al. (2014), with the important difference that Italy is a highly centralised state where institutions and policies are ‘de jure’ the same in all provinces. This suggests that something beyond institutional and policy differences also shapes intergenerational mobility.

Get the paper
To top

Intergenerational Mobility and the Informative Content of Surnames

Joint with Maia Guell (University of Edinburgh) and Chris Telmer (CMU)

Review of Economic Studies DOI

We propose a new methodology for measuring intergenerational mobility in economic wellbeing. Our method is based on the joint distribution of surnames and economic outcomes. It circumvents the need for intergenerational panel data, a long-standing stumbling block for understanding mobility. A single cross-sectional dataset is sufficient. Our main idea is simple. If "inheritance" is important for economic outcomes, then rare surnames should predict economic outcomes in the cross-section. This is because rare surnames are indicative of familial linkages. Of course, if the number of rare surnames is small, this will not work. But rare surnames are abundant in the highly-skewed nature of surname distributions from most Western societies.

We develop a model that articulates this idea and shows that the more important is inheritance, the more informative will be surnames. This result is robust to a variety of different assumptions about fertility and mating. We apply our method using the 2001 census from Catalonia, a large region of Spain. We use educational attainment as a proxy for overall economic well-being. A calibration exercise results in an estimate of the intergenerational correlation coefficient of 0:60. We also find evidence suggesting that mobility has decreased among the different generations of the 20th century. A complementary analysis based on sibling correlations confirms our results and provides a robustness check on our method. Our model and our data allow us to examine one possible explanation for the observed decrease in mobility. We find that the degree of assortative mating has increased over time. Overall, we argue that our method has promise because it can tap the vast mines of census data that are available in a heretofore unexploited manner.

Get the paper

Online Appendix

Get the presentation slides

To top

Who is Afraid of a Globalized World? Foreign Direct Investments,Local Knowledge and Allocation of Talents

Joint with Giovanni Pica (Universita di Salerno and CSEF)

Journal of International Economics

DOI

We study the distributional effects of globalization within a model of heterogeneous agents where both managerial talent and knowledge of the local economic environment are required in order to set up a firm in a given country. Therefore, agents willing to set up a firm in a foreign country need to incur a learning cost that depends on how different is the foreign entrepreneurial environments from the domestic one. In this context, we show that globalization fosters FDI and raises wages, output and productivity. Moreover, it benefits workers and highly talented multinational entrepreneurs, while harming low-ability domestic producers. The effects of openness follow from highly efficient foreign entrepreneurs driving inefficient local firms out of the market. We provide empirical evidence consistent with the implications of the model, showing a significant negative effect of the distance between nationwide regulations indexes on bilateral FDI flows.

Get the paper

Get the presentation slides

To top

It is Hobbes, not Rousseau: An Experiment on Social Insurance

Joint with Antonio Cabrales (Universidad Carlos III) and Rosemarie Nagel(UPF)

Experimental Economics

DOI

We perform an experiment on social insurance to provide a laboratory replica of some important features of the welfare state. In the experiment, all individuals in a group decide whether to make a costly effort, which produces a random (independent) outcome for each one of them. The group members then vote on whether to redistribute the resulting and commonly known total sum of earnings equally amongst themselves. This game has two equilibria, if played once. In one of them, all players make effort and there is little redistribution. In the other one, there is no effort and nothing to redistribute. A solution to the repeated game allows for redistribution and high effort, by the threat to revert to the worst of these equilibria. Our results show that redistribution with high effort is not sustainable. The main reason for the absence of redistribution is that rich agents do not act differently depending on whether the poor have worked hard or not. There is no social contract by which redistribution may be sustained by the threat of punishing the poor if they do not exert effort. Thus, the explanation of the behavior of the subjects lies in Hobbes, not in Rousseau.

Get the paper
To top

Temporary Contracts, Incentives and Unemployment

Joint with Maia Guell (University of Edinburgh)

DOI

Firing-cost-free temporary contracts were introduced in Europe during the 1980’s in order to fight unemployment in a context of high firing costs that were politically hard to decrease. Since then, they have become a prevalent labor market institution in many countries. Yet evidence indicates that these contracts have not been successful at bringing down unemployment levels. In this paper we argue that the rational for the introduction of temporary contracts is flawed at its root. We provide a novel explanation of why temporary contracts increase unemployment even in a context where a reduction of firing costs would actually reduce unemployment. We argue that, if minimum wages are kept at high levels, temporary contracts have an effect not unlike an increase of unemployment benefits. By increasing the flows in and out of unemployment into relatively highly paid temporary jobs (minimum wage), they increase the value of being unemployed. This has a negative effect on the incentives to work for permanent workers, increases their efficiency wages and reduces the willingness of firms to create employment. We present empirical evidence compatible with the main implications of the model.

Get the paper

Get the presentation slides

To top

The Misallocation of Talent

DOI

This is a non technical paper !!!!

This is a non technical paper.

I explain why the market does not provide with an efficient allocation of talent to tasks. I also explain why we should expect that more social mobility goes in parallel with the degree of efficiency in the allocation of people to tasks, so that if we observe that a society has more intergenerational mobility than another, it is a sign that it is also a healthier, more efficient economy. Finally, I explain why it is difficult to measure intergenerational mobility, and give some suggestions on how try to tackle the problem.

This paper helps to make sense of more than half of my research.

Get the paper
To top

Inequality and Mobility

Joint with John Hassler (IIES, Stockholm University) and Joseph Zeira (Hebrew University)

Journal of Economic Growth

DOI

Acknowledging that wage inequality and intergenerational mobility are strongly interrelated, this paper presents a model in which both are jointly determined. The model enables us to study how inequality and mobility are affected by exogenous changes and what determines their correlation. A main implication of the model is that differences in the amount of public subsidies to education and educational quality produce cross-country patterns with a negative correlation between inequality and mobility. Differences in the labor market, like differences in skill-biased technology or wage compression instead produce a positive correlation. The predictions of the model are found to be consistent with various empirical observations on mobility and inequality.

Get the paper
To top

Unemployment Insurance Design: inducing moving and retraining

European Economic Review

DOI

Evidence suggests that unemployed individuals can sometimes affect their job prospects by undertaking a costly action like deciding to move or retrain. Realistically, such an opportunity only arises for some individuals and the identity of those may be unobservable ex- ante. The problem of characterizing constrained optimal unemployment insurance in this case has been neglected in previous literature. We construct a model of optimal unemployment insurance where multiple incentive constraints are easily handled. The model is used to analyze the case when an incentive constraint involving moving costs must be respected in addition to the standard constraint involving costly unobservable job-search. Absent wealth effects on behavior, we derive closed-form solutions showing that when the moving/retraining incentive constraint binds, unemployment bene?ts should increase over the unemployment spell, with an initial period with low benefi?ts and an increase after this period has expired.

Get the paper
To top

Political commitment and loss aversion

Joint with John Hassler (IIES, Stockholm University)

DOI

At least since the work of Kydland and Prescott (1977), it is acknowledged that the ability for policy makers to commit to future policies often is of key importance for outomces and welfare. An example is capital income taxation, where the commitment solution typically involve zero capital income taxes after some initial periods, while no commitment may imply empirically much too high taxes. A more realistic intermediate outcome can be supported by trigger strategies where a deviation from a "good" equilibrium is punished by a possibly in?nite revertion to a "bad" Nash-equilibrium. In a political economy setting, the degree of coordination between voters of di¤erent generations required to sustain such an equilibrium is large, arguably unreasonably large. We propose loss-aversion as an alternative explanation for how a commitment-like equilibrium can arise. We set up a politico-economic OLG-model where individuals make investments and dynamically form reference points for future consumption, around which they are loss-averse. Without loss-aversion, the only Markov equilibrium involves 100% taxation of any investments and trigger strategies are required to sustain lower taxes and positive investments. With loss-aversion, we ?nd a Markov equilibrium with positive investments. In contrast to the case of trigger strategies, this equilibrium is renegotiation proof and independent of discounting, surviving also for arbitrarily high rates of discounting.

Get the paper

Get the presentation slides

To top

The Effect of GNP Announcements on Fluctuations of GNP Growth

Joint with Paul Schulstald (God knows where)

European Economic Review

DOI

The meat of the paper is in the data on anouncements of GNP growth. This file contains the anouncements of quaterly US GNP growth. (Range: 1967.1 - 1991.4). Observation at time t (say first quarter of 1990) indicates the anouncement made at the begining of t (first quarter of 1990) of which was the GNP growth during t-1 (last quarter of 1989). Source: Survey of Current Business. Read paper for more information.

This paper is an empirical study of the degree in which perceptions affect the evolution of the economy. We study the effects of the announcements that the government makes on GNP growth. These announcements are subject to a substantial degree of noise and its accuracy improves with time. A revised number is published several years after the first announcement was made public. We consider that the final revision is the ?true? value of GNP growth. We show that once announcements are taken into account, the true value of GNP growth at time t has no predictive power in determining growth at any future time. All the predictive power lies in the announcements, and not in the true level of growth. Actually, we show that the variable that determines future growth is the unexpected part of the announcements. We also show that announcements affect growth via aggregate investment.

Get the paper
To top

A Positive Theory of Geographic Mobility and Social Insurance

With John Hassler, Kjetil Storesletten and Fabrizio Zilibotti

International Economic Review

DOI

This article presents a tractable dynamic general equilibrium model explaining cross-country data on geographical mobility, unemployment, and labor market institutions. Rational forward-looking agents vote on unemployment insurance (UI). Agents with higher moving costs (larger attachment to their location) prefer more generous UI. Attachment is assumed to increase with the duration of residence. UI mitigates incentives for moving and increases, therefore, the fraction of attached agents and the political support for UI. This self-reinforcing mechanism can yield two steady-states: one “European” and one “American.” The former (latter) features high (low) unemployment, low (high) geographical mobility, and high (low) UI.

To top

The Survival of the Welfare State

With John Hassler, Kjetil Storesletten and Fabrizio Zilibotti

American Economic Review

DOI

This paper provides an analytical characterization of Markov perfect equilibria in a model with repeated voting, where agents vote over distortionary income redistribution. A key result is that the future constituency for redistributive policies depends positively on current redistribution, since this affects both private investments and the future distribution of voters. The model features multiple equilibria. In some equilibria, positive redistribution persists forever. In other equilibria, even a majority of beneficiaries of redistribution vote strategically so as to induce the end of the welfare state next period. Skill-biased technical change makes the survival of the welfare state less likely.

To top

Intelligence, Social Mobility, and Growth

With John Hassler

AER

DOI

We develop a model where the allocation of human resources, intergenerational social mobility, and technological growth are jointly determined. High growth endogenously increases the equilibrium return to innate cognitive ability and makes the allocation of individuals depend more on innate ability and less on social background. Individuals with a higher level of innate cognitive ability can deal better with less known, but more productive, technologies and thus choose a higher rate of technological growth. A social allocation based on innate ability and high growth will thus reinforce each other, implying the possibility of multiple endogenous growth equilibria.

To top

Employment Turnover and the Public Allocation of Unemployment Insurance

With John Hassler

Journal of Public Economics

DOI

Unemployment benefits are higher and turnover between unemployment and employment is lower in Europe than in the U.S. We model the political determination of the unemployment insurance to explain these differences. We show that saving and borrowing is a good substitute for unemployment insurance when turnover is high. With high turnover, the median voter thus prefers low unemployment insurance. With low turnover, generous unemployment insurance becomes more valuable. If the median voter cannot bind future voters, the voting cycle must, however, be long in order to support a high level of insurance. Endogenizing turnover produces the possibility of multiple political equilibria.

To top

Shared Knowledge

DOI

Agents use their knowledge on the history of the economy in order to choose what is the optimal action to take at any given moment of time, but each individual observes history with some idiosyncratic noise. Thus, different agents will have different observations and beliefs. As long as the level of idiosyncratic noise is an endogenous variable, the degree of heterogeneity in the beliefs (and actions) of the agents will also be endogenously generated. We present a dynamic model of social learning in which the returns of the different activities follow independently distributed stationary Markov processes. Each period the agents receive unbiased noisy signals on the payoff of each sector. The signals differ across agents, but all of them have the same variance, which depends on their aggregate behavior. The degree of heterogeneity across agents is then an endogenous variable, evolving across time, which determines, and is determined by, the amount of information disclosed. As long as both the level of social interaction and the underlying precision of the observations are relatively large there will be an excessive concentration of the investment in a few sectors, the agents' beliefs being very homogeneous most of the time, but with periods of heterogeneity, learning and reallocation of resources following recessions.

Get the paper
To top

Spirits, but not so Animal

DOI

This paper stresses the importance of information diffusion problems in the business cycles. It shows that it is possible to modelize ``animal spirits'' in a context of perfectly rational and forward-looking agents whose only source of information is their perception on the past behaviour of the economy. In the animal spirits equilibrium the economy will move from booms to recessions according to changes in the optimism of the agents. These changes are due to what they \emph{percieve} that was the past evolution of the economy \textit{not to the presence of exogenous coordination devices or shocks}. Agents use their perception of the past in order to forecast what will happen in the future. Each of them collects her information by observing the actions taken by a different sample of individuals. Consequently, the perceptions are noisy (no agent is ever sure that what she sees is what really happened) and may differ across agents. The amount of noise that agents face is in itself an endogenous variable, a product of the state of the economy. The stochastic dynamic structure of the aggregates is then endogenous and mimics business cycle behaviour.

Get the paper
To top

Para todos los públicos.

To top

Sobre desigualdad y herencia.

Es el tema que más me interesa. Desigualdad, sobre todo de oportunidades.

¿Qué la ocasiona? ¿Cuánta desigualdad hay? ¿Cuánto heredamos de nuestros padres? ¿Qué papel debería tener el estado para controlarla?

"De los apellidos de los catalanes" , con Maia Güell. Nada es Gratis, 22/09/2015.

Una explicación de nuestro paper sobre apellidos en Cataluña, con una derivación hacia cómo la división "étnica" tiene una manifestación política.

"Experimento con final descorazonador" , con Antonio Cabrales. La Vanguardia, 30-12-2012.

Una explicación de nuestro paper, una mirada a lo que subyace detrás del estado del bienestar y una explicación de porqué Hobbes fue el primer científico social y Rousseau un iluso.

"Muy desiguales", Claves de Razón Práctica, 221, Marzo 2012.

"La asignación ineficiente del talento". Opuscles del Crei, 22. Mayo 2009.

Esta era mi opinión sobre el tema hace unos años.. mi opinión ha cambiado desde entonces. Ahora tengo muchas menos certezas.

To top

Sobre el nacionalismo, esa enorme pesadez.

"De los apellidos de los catalanes" , con Maia Güell. Nada es Gratis, 22/09/2015.

Una explicación de nuestro paper sobre apellidos en Cataluña, con una derivación hacia cómo la división "étnica" tiene una manifestación política.